Tariffs in United States history
Graph: Share of tariff revenues in U.S. Federal budget.
Tariffs in United States history have played important roles in trade policy, political debates and the nation's economic history. The main goal of the tariff was money to pay the federal budget. Controversy arose over whether manufacturing interests were favored and consumer interests hurt by high tariffs. The 1st United States Congress, wanting a straightforward tax that was not too onerous and easy to collect, passed the Tariff Act of 1789. Treasury agents collected the tariff before goods could be landed, and what became the Coast Guard prevented smuggling. Tariffs were the largest (approaching 95% at times) source of federal revenue until the Federal income tax began after 1913. For well over a century the federal government was largely financed by tariffs averaging about 20% on foreign imports. There are no tariffs for imports or shipments from other states. Since the 1940s, foreign trade policies have focused more on reciprocal tariffs and low tariff rates rather than using tariffs as a significant source of Federal tax revenue. The goal of using higher tariffs to promote industrialization was urged by the first Secretary of the Treasury, Alexander Hamilton, and after him the Whig Party. They generally failed because Jeffersonian and Jacksonian Democrats said the tariff should be only high enough to pay the government's bills; otherwise, it would hurt the consumers. The Republicans, however, made high tariffs the centerpiece of their economic policy beginning in 1861, and as late as 1930. Since 1930, tariffs have not been a major political issue.
Tariff revenues
Tariffs were the main source of all Federal revenue from 1790 to 1914. At the end of the American Civil War in 1865 about 63% of Federal income was generated by the excise taxes, which exceeded the 25.4% generated by tariffs. In 1915 during World War I tariffs generated only 30.1% of revenues. Since 1935 tariff income has continued to be a declining percentage of Federal tax income.
U.S. Historical Tariffs (Customs) Collections by Federal Government (All dollar amounts are in millions of U.S. dollars)[1][2][3][4][5][6] | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Year | Tariff Income | Budget % Tariff | Federal Receipts | Income Tax | Payroll Tax | Average Tariff |
1792 | $4.4 | 95.0% | $4.6 | $- | $- | 15.1% |
1795 | $5.6 | 91.6% | $6.1 | $- | $- | 8.0% |
1800 | $9.1 | 83.7% | $10.8 | $- | $- | 10.0% |
1805 | $12.9 | 95.4% | $13.6 | $- | $- | 10.7% |
1810 | $8.6 | 91.5% | $9.4 | $- | $- | 10.1% |
1815 | $7.3 | 46.4% | $15.7 | $- | $- | 6.5% |
1820 | $15.0 | 83.9% | $17.9 | $- | $- | 20.2% |
1825 | $20.1 | 97.9% | $20.5 | $- | $- | 22.3% |
1830 | $21.9 | 88.2% | $24.8 | $- | $- | 35.0% |
1835 | $19.4 | 54.1% | $35.8 | $- | $- | 14.2% |
1840 | $12.5 | 64.2% | $19.5 | $- | $- | 12.7% |
1845 | $27.5 | 91.9% | $30.0 | $- | $- | 24.3% |
1850 | $39.7 | 91.0% | $43.6 | $- | $- | 22.9% |
1855 | $53.0 | 81.2% | $65.4 | $- | $- | 20.6% |
1860 | $53.2 | 94.9% | $56.1 | $- | $- | 15.0% |
1863 | $63.0 | 55.9% | $112.7 | $- | $- | 25.9% |
1864 | $102.3 | 38.7% | $264.6 | $- | $- | 32.3% |
1865 | $84.9 | 25.4% | $333.7 | $61.0 | $- | 35.6% |
1870 | $194.5 | 47.3% | $411.3 | $37.8 | $- | 44.6% |
1875 | $157.2 | 54.6% | $288.0 | $- | $- | 36.1% |
1880 | $184.5 | 55.3% | $333.5 | $- | $- | 27.6% |
1885 | $181.5 | 56.1% | $323.7 | $- | $- | 32.6% |
1890 | $229.7 | 57.0% | $403.1 | $- | $- | 27.6% |
1900 | $233.2 | 41.1% | $567.2 | $- | $- | 27.4% |
1910 | $233.7 | 34.6% | $675.2 | $- | $- | 15.0% |
1913 | $318.8 | 44.0% | $724.1 | $35.0 | $- | 17.6% |
1915 | $209.8 | 30.1% | $697.9 | $47.0 | $- | 12.5% |
1916 | $213.7 | 27.3% | $782.5 | $121.0 | $- | 8.9% |
1917 | $225.9 | 20.1% | $1,124.3 | $373.0 | $- | 7.7% |
1918 | $947.0 | 25.8% | $3,664.6 | $2,720.0 | $- | 31.2% |
1920 | $886.0 | 13.2% | $6,694.6 | $4,032.0 | $- | 16.8% |
1925 | $547.6 | 14.5% | $3,780.1 | $1,697.0 | $- | 13.0% |
1928 | $566.0 | 14.0% | $4,042.3 | $2,088.0 | $- | 13.8% |
1930 | $587.0 | 14.1% | $4,177.9 | $2,300.0 | $- | 19.2% |
1935 | $318.8 | 8.4% | $3,800.5 | $1,100.0 | $- | 15.6% |
1940 | $331.0 | 6.1% | $5,387.1 | $2,100.0 | $800.0 | 12.6% |
1942 | $369.0 | 2.9% | $12,799.1 | $7,900.0 | $1,200.0 | 13.4% |
1944 | $417.0 | 0.9% | $44,148.9 | $34,400.0 | $1,900.0 | 10.6% |
1946 | $424.0 | 0.9% | $46,400.0 | $28,000.0 | $1,900.0 | 7.7% |
1948 | $408.0 | 0.9% | $47,300.0 | $29,000.0 | $2,500.0 | 5.5% |
1950 | $407.0 | 0.9% | $43,800.0 | $26,200.0 | $3,000.0 | 4.5% |
1951 | $609.0 | 1.1% | $56,700.0 | $35,700.0 | $4,100.0 | 5.5% |
1955 | $585.0 | 0.8% | $71,900.0 | $46,400.0 | $6,100.0 | 5.1% |
1960 | $1,105.0 | 1.1% | $99,800.0 | $62,200.0 | $12,200.0 | 7.3% |
1965 | $1,442.0 | 1.2% | $116,800.0 | $74,300.0 | $22,200.0 | 6.7% |
1970 | $2,430.0 | 1.3% | $192,800.0 | $123,200.0 | $44,400.0 | 6.0% |
1975 | $3,676.0 | 1.3% | $279,100.0 | $163,000.0 | $84,500.0 | 3.7% |
1980 | $7,174.0 | 1.4% | $517,100.0 | $308,700.0 | $157,800.0 | 2.9% |
1985 | $12,079.0 | 1.6% | $734,000.0 | $395,900.0 | $255,200.0 | 3.6% |
1990 | $11,500.0 | 1.1% | $1,032,000.0 | $560,400.0 | $380,000.0 | 2.8% |
1995 | $19,301.0 | 1.4% | $1,361,000.0 | $747,200.0 | $484,500.0 | 2.6% |
2000 | $19,914.0 | 1.0% | $2,025,200.0 | $1,211,700.0 | $652,900.0 | 1.6% |
2005 | $23,379.0 | 1.1% | $2,153,600.0 | $1,205,500.0 | $794,100.0 | 1.4% |
2010 | $25,298.0 | 1.2% | $2,162,700.0 | $1,090,000.0 | $864,800.0 | 1.3% |
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- | ||||||
Notes: All dollar amounts are in millions of U.S. dollars Income taxes include Individual and Corporate taxes Federal expenditures often exceed Revenue by temporary borrowings. Initially the U.S. Federal Government was financed mainly by customs(tariffs Average Tariff Rate % = Customs Revenue/ cost of Imports (goods). Other taxes collected are: Income Tax, Corporate Income Tax, Inheritance, Tariffs—often called Customs or duties on imports, etc. Income Taxes began in 1913 with the passage of 16th Amendment. Payroll taxes are Social Security and Medicare taxes Payroll Taxes began in 1940. Many Federal government Excise taxes are assigned to Trust Funds and are collected for and “dedicated” to a particular Trust. Sources: |
Wikisource has original text related to this article: |
This article is part of a series on |
Taxation in the United States of America |
---|
United States portal |
The U.S. Constitution of 1789 gave the federal government authority to tax, stating that Congress has the power to "... lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts and excises, pay the debts and provide for the common defense and general welfare of the United States." and also "To regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian Tribes." Tariffs between states is prohibited by the U.S. Constitution, and all domestically made products can be imported or shipped to another state tax-free.
Tariffs and Political parties
The tariff issue was central to political party debates in the Second Party System, Third Party System and Fourth Party System, from the 1820s to the early 1930s. In general Democrats favored a tariff that would pay the cost of government, but no higher. Whigs and Republicans favored higher tariffs to encourage or "protect" industry and industrial workers. Tariffs were generally low before 1860, and high after that. Since the 1930s, however, tariffs have been very low and have been much less a matter of partisan debate.
History and background
It should be noted that the adjacent table determines the average tariff by calculating the ratio of customs duties collected to the total value of dutiable *and* duty-free items. It therefore significantly understates the average tariff applied to any items having a tariff. For example, using the same source as cited by the table, the average tariff in 1915 was over 33% for those items that had a tariff. The 12.5% ratio listed in the table can only be derived by including the value of all items imported that did not even have a tariff.
Colonial Era to 1789
In the colonial era, before 1775, nearly every colony levied its own tariffs, usually with lower rates for British products. There were taxes on ships (on a tonnage basis), import taxes on slaves, export taxes on tobacco, and import taxes on alcoholic beverages.[11] The London government insisted on a policy of mercantilism whereby only British ships could trade in the colonies. In defiance, some American merchants engaged in smuggling.[12][13]
During the Revolution, the British blockade from 1775 to 1783 largely ended foreign trade. In the 1783–89 period, each state set up its own trade rules, often imposing tariffs or restrictions on neighboring states. The new Constitution, which went into effect in 1789, banned interstate tariffs or trade restrictions, as well as state taxes on exports.[14]
Early National period, 1789–1828
Responding to an urgent need for revenue and a trade imbalance with England that was fast destroying the infant American industries and draining the nation of its currency, the First United States Congress passed, and President George Washington signed, the Hamilton Tariff of 1789, which authorized the collection of duties on imported goods. Customs duties as set by tariff rates up to 1860 were usually about 80–95% of all federal revenue. Having just fought a war over taxation (among other things) the U.S. Congress wanted a reliable source of income that was relatively unobtrusive and easy to collect. It also sought to protect the infant industries that had developed during the war but which were now threatened by cheaper imports, especially from England. Tariffs and excise taxes were authorized by the United States Constitution and recommended by the first United States Secretary of the Treasury, Alexander Hamilton in 1789 to tax foreign imports and set up low excise taxes on whiskey and a few other products to provide the Federal Government with enough money to pay its operating expenses and to redeem at full value U.S. Federal debts and the debts the states had accumulated during the Revolutionary War. The Congress set low excise taxes on only a few goods, such as, whiskey, rum, tobacco, snuff and refined sugar. The tax on whiskey was highly controversial and set of massive protests by Western Farmers in the Whiskey Rebellion of 1794, which was suppressed by General Washington at the head of an army. The whiskey excise tax collected so little and was so despised it was abolished by President Thomas Jefferson in 1802.[15]
All tariffs were on a long list of goods (dutiable goods) with different customs rates and some goods on a "free" list. Congress spent enormous amounts of time figuring out these tariff import tax schedules.
With tariffs providing the basic federal revenue, an embargo on trade, or an enemy blockade, would threaten havoc. This happened in connection with the American economic warfare against Britain in the 1807-15 period. In 1807 imports dropped by more than half and some products became much more expensive or unobtainable. Congress passed the Embargo Act of 1807 and the Non-Intercourse Act (1809) to punish British and French governments for their actions; unfortunately their main effect was to reduce imports even more. The War of 1812 brought a similar set of problems as U.S. trade was again restricted by British naval blockades. The fiscal crisis was made much worse by the abolition of the First Bank of the U.S., which was the national bank. It was reestablished right after the war.[16]
The lack of imported goods relatively quickly gave very strong incentives to start building several U.S. industries in the Northeast. Textiles and machinery especially grew. Many new industries were set up and run profitably during the wars and about half of them failed after hostilities ceased and normal imports resumed. Industry in the U.S. was advancing up the skill set, innovation knowledge and organization curve.
The Tariff Act of 1789 imposed the first national source of revenue for the newly formed United States. The new U.S. Constitution ratified in 1789, allowed only the federal government to levy uniform tariffs. Only the federal government could set tariff rates (customs), so the old system of separate state rates disappeared. The new law taxed all imports at rates from 5 to 15 percent. These rates were primarily designed to generate revenue to pay the annual expenses of the federal government and the national debt and the debts the states had accumulated during the American War of Independence and to also promote manufactures and independence from foreign nations, especially for defense needs. Hamilton believed that all Revolutionary War debt should be paid in full to establish and keep U.S. financial credibility. In addition to income in his Report on Manufactures Treasury Secretary Alexander Hamilton proposed a far-reaching plan to use protective tariffs as a lever for rapid industrialization. In the late 18th century the industrial age was just starting and the United States had little or no textile industry—the heart of the early Industrial Revolution. The British government having just lost the Revolutionary War tried to maintain their near monopoly on cheap and efficient textile manufacturing by prohibiting the export of textile machines, machine models or the emigration of people familiar with these machines. Clothing in the early United States was nearly all hand made by a very time consuming and expensive process—just like it had been made for centuries before. The new textile manufacturing techniques in Britain were often over thirty times cheaper as well as being easier to use, more efficient and productive. Hamilton believed that a stiff tariff on imports would not only raise income but "protect" and help subsidize early efforts at setting up manufacturing facilities that could compete with British products.[17]
Samuel Slater in 1789 emigrated (illegally since he was familiar with textile manufacturing) from Britain. Looking for opportunities he heard of the failing attempts at making cotton mills in Pawtucket, Rhode Island. Contacting the owners he promised to see if he could fix their mills—they offered him a full partnership if he succeeded. Declaring their early attempts unworkable he proceeded from January 1790 to December 1790 to build the first operational textile manufacturing facility in the United States. The Industrial Revolution was off and running in the United States. Initially the cost of their textiles was slightly higher than the cost of equivalent British goods but the tariff helped protect their early start-up industry.[18]
The high protectionism tariffs Hamilton originally called for were not adopted until after the War of 1812, when nationalists such as Henry Clay and John C. Calhoun saw the need for more federal income and more industry. In wartime, they declared, having a home industry was a necessity to avoid shortages. Likewise owners of the small new factories that were springing up in the northeast to mass-produce boots, hats, nails and other common items wanted higher tariffs that would significantly protect them for a time from more efficient British producers. A 10% discount on the customs tax was offered on items imported in American ships, so that the American merchant marine would be supported.[19]
Once industrialization and mass production started, the demand for higher and higher tariffs came from manufacturers and factory workers. They believed that their businesses should be protected from the lower wages and more efficient factories of Britain and the rest of Europe. Nearly every northern Congressman was eager to logroll a higher tariff rate for his local industry. Senator Daniel Webster, formerly a spokesperson for Boston's merchants who imported goods (and wanted low tariffs), switched dramatically to represent the manufacturing interests in the Tariff of 1824. Rates were especially high for bolts of cloth and for bar iron, of which Britain was a low-cost producer. The culmination came in the Tariff of 1828, ridiculed by free traders as the "Tariff of Abominations", with import custom duties averaging over 25 percent. Intense political opposition to higher tariffs came from Southern Democrats and plantation owners in South Carolina who had little manufacturing industry and imported some products with high tariffs. They would have to pay more for imports. They claimed their economic interest was being unfairly injured. They attempted to "nullify" the federal tariff and spoke of secession from the Union (see the Nullification Crisis). President Andrew Jackson let it be known he would use the U.S. Army to enforce the law, and no state supported the South Carolina call for nullification. A compromise ended the crisis included a lowering of the average tariff rate over ten years to a rate of 15% to 20%.[20]
Second Party System
Tariffs soon became a major political issue as the Whigs (1832-1852) and (after 1854) the Republicans wanted to protect their mostly northern industries and constituents by voting for higher tariffs and the Southern Democrats, which had very little industry but imported many goods voted for lower tariffs. Each party as it came into power voted to raise or lower tariffs under the constraints that the Federal Government always needed a certain level of revenues. The United States public debt was paid off in 1834 and President Andrew Jackson, a strong Southern Democrat, oversaw the cutting of the tariff rates roughly in half and eliminating nearly all federal excise taxes in about 1835.
Henry Clay and his Whig Party, envisioning a rapid modernization based on highly productive factories, sought a high tariff. Their key argument was that startup factories, or "infant industries", would at first be less efficient than European (British) producers. Furthermore, American factory workers were paid higher wages than their European competitors. The arguments proved highly persuasive in industrial districts. Clay's position was adopted in the 1828 and 1832 Tariff Acts. The Nullification Crisis forced a partial abandonment of the Whig position. When the Whigs won victories in the 1840 and 1842 elections, taking control of Congress, they re-instituted higher tariffs with the Tariff of 1842.[21] In examining these debates Moore finds that they were not precursors to Civil War. Instead they looked backward and continued the old debate whether foreign trade policy should embrace free trade or protectionism.[22]
Walker Tariff
The Democrats won in 1845, electing James K. Polk as president. Polk succeeded in passing the Walker tariff of 1846 by uniting the rural and agricultural factions of the entire country for lower tariffs. They sought a level of a "tariff for revenue only" that would pay the cost of government but not show favoritism to one section or economic sector at the expense of another. The Walker Tariff actually increased trade with Britain and others and brought in more revenue to the federal treasury than the higher tariff. The average tariff on the Walker Tariff was about 25%. While protectionists in Pennsylvania and neighboring states were angered, the South achieved its goal of setting low tariff rates before the Civil War.[23]
Low tariff of 1857
The Walker Tariff remained in place until 1857, when a nonpartisan coalition lowered them again with the Tariff of 1857 to 18%. This was in response to the British repeal of their protectionist "Corn Laws".[24]
The Democrats in Congress, dominated by Southern Democrats, wrote and passed the tariff laws in the 1830s, 1840s, and 1850s, and kept reducing rates, so that the 1857 rates were down to about 15%, a move that boosted trade so overwhelmingly that revenues actually increased from just over $20 million in 1840 to more than $80 million by 1856.[25] The South had almost no complaints but the low rates angered many Northern industrialists and factory workers, especially in Pennsylvania, who demanded protection for their growing iron industry. The Republican Party replaced the Whigs in 1854 and also favored high tariffs to stimulate industrial growth; it was part of the 1860 Republican platform.
The Morrill Tariff significantly raising tariff rates became possible only after the Southern Senators walked out of Congress when their states left the Union, leaving a Republican majority. It was signed by Democratic President James Buchanan in early March 1861 shortly before President Abraham Lincoln took office. Pennsylvania iron mills and New England woolen mills mobilized businessmen and workers to call for high tariffs, but Republican merchants wanted low tariffs. The high tariff advocates lost in 1857, but stepped up their campaign by blaming the economic recession of 1857 on the lower rates. Economist Henry Charles Carey of Philadelphia was the most outspoken advocate, along with Horace Greeley and his influential newspaper, the New York Tribune. Increases were finally enacted in February 1861 after Southerners resigned their seats in Congress on the eve of the Civil War.[26][27]
Some historians in recent decades have minimized the tariff issue as a cause of the war, noting that few people in 1860–61 said it was of central importance to them. Compromises were proposed in 1860-61 to save the Union, but they did not involve the tariff.[28] Arguably, the effects of a tariff enacted in March 1861 could have made little impact upon any delegation which met prior to its signing. It is indicative of the Northern industrial supported and anti-agrarian position of that 1861 Republican controlled congress. Some secessionist documents do mention a tariff issue, though not nearly as often as the preservation of the impactful economic institution of slavery. However, a few libertarian economists place more importance on the tariff issue.[29]
Civil War
During the war far more revenue was needed, so the rates were raised again and again, along with many other taxes such as excise taxes on luxuries and income taxes on the rich.[30] By far most of the wartime government revenue came from bonds and loans ($2.6 billion), not taxes ($357 million) or tariffs ($305 million).[31]
The Morrill Tariff took effect a few weeks before the war began on April 12, 1861, and was not collected in the South. The Confederate States of America (CSA) passed its own tariff of about 15% on most items, including many items that previously were duty-free from the North. Previously tariffs between states were prohibited. The Confederates believed that they could finance their government by tariffs. The anticipated tariff revenue never appeared as the Union Navy blockaded their ports and the Union army restricted their trade with the Northern states. The Confederacy collected a mere $3.5 million in tariff revenue from the Civil War start to end and had to resort to inflation and confiscation instead for revenue.[32]
Gilded Age
Reconstruction Era
Historian Howard K. Beale argued that high tariffs were needed during the Civil War, but were retained after the war for the benefit of Northern industrialists, who would otherwise lose markets and profits. To keep political control of Congress, Beale argued, Northern Industrialists worked through the Republican Party and supported Reconstruction policies that kept low-tariff Southern whites out of power. The Beale thesis was widely disseminated by the influential survey of Charles A. Beard, The Rise of American Civilization (1927).[33][34]
In the late 1950s historians rejected the Beale-Beard thesis by showing that Northern businessmen were evenly divided on the tariff, and were not using Reconstruction policies to support it.[35][36]
Politics of protection
The iron and steel industry, and the wool industry, were the well-organized interests groups that demanded (and usually obtained) high tariffs through support of the Republican Party. Industrial workers had much higher wages than their European counterparts, and they creditied it to the tariff and voted Republican.[37]
Democrats were divided on the issue, in large part because of pro-tariff elements in the Pennsylvania party who wanted to protect the growing iron industry, as well as pockets of high tariff support in nearby industrializing states.[38] However President Grover Cleveland made low tariffs the centerpiece of Democratic Party policies in the late 1880s. His argument is that high tariffs were an unnecessary and unfair tax on consumers. The South and West generally supported low tariffs, and the industrial East high tariffs.[39] Republican William McKinley was the outstanding spokesman for high tariffs, promising it would bring prosperity for all groups.[40][41]
After the Civil War, high tariffs remained as the Republican Party remained in office and the Southern Democrats were restricted from office. Advocates insisted that tariffs brought prosperity to the nation as a whole and no one was really injured. As industrialization proceeded apace throughout the Northeast, some Democrats, especially Pennsylvanians, became high tariff advocates.
Farmers and wool
The Republican high tariff advocates appealed to farmers with the theme that high-wage factory workers would pay premium prices for foodstuffs. This was the "home market" idea, and it won over most farmers in the Northeast, but it had little relevance to the southern and western farmers who exported most of their cotton, tobacco and wheat. In the late 1860s the wool manufacturers (based near Boston and Philadelphia) formed the first national lobby, and cut deals with wool-growing farmers in several states. Their challenge was that fastidious wool producers in Britain and Australia marketed a higher quality fleece than the careless Americans, and that British manufacturers had costs as low as the American mills. The result was a wool tariff that helped the farmers by a high rate on imported wool—a tariff the American manufacturers had to pay—together with a high tariff on finished woolens and worsted goods.[42]
U.S. industry dominates the world
Apart from wool and woolens, American industry and agriculture—and industrial workers—had become the most efficient in the world by the 1880s as they took the lead in the worldwide Industrial Revolution. They were not at risk from cheap imports. No other country had the industrial capacity, large market, the high efficiency and low costs, or the complex distribution system needed to compete in the vast American market. Indeed, it was the British who watched in stunned horror as cheaper American products flooded their home islands. Wailed the London Daily Mail in 1900,
"We have lost to the American manufacturer electrical machinery, locomotives, steel rails, sugar-producing and agricultural machinery, and latterly even stationary engines, the pride and backbone of the British engineering industry."
Nevertheless, some American manufacturers and union workers demanded the high tariff be maintained. The tariff represented a complex balance of forces. Railroads, for example, consumed vast quantities of steel. To the extent tariffs raised steel prices, they paid much more making possible the U.S steel industry's massive investment to expand capacity and switch to the Bessemer process and later to the open hearth furnace. Between 1867 and 1900 U.S. steel production increased more than 500 times from 22,000 tons to 11,400,000 tons and Bessemer steel rails, first made in the U.S that would last 18 years under heavy traffic, would come to replace the old wrought iron rail that could only endure two years under light service.[43] Taussig says that in 1881, British steel rails sold for $31 a ton, and if Americans imported them they paid a $28/ton tariff, giving $59/ton for an imported ton of rails. American mills charged $61 a ton—and made a huge profit, which was then reinvested into increased capacity, higher quality steels and more efficient production.[44] By 1897 the American steel rail price had dropped to $19.60 per ton compared to the British price at $21.00 - not including the $7.84 duty charge - demonstrating that the tariff had performed its purpose of giving the industry time to become competitive.[45] Then the U.S. steel industry became an exporter of steel rail to England selling below the British price and during WW I would become the largest supplier of steel to the allies. From 1915 through 1918, the largest American steel company, U.S. Steel, alone delivered more steel each year than Germany and Austria-Hungary combined, totalling 99,700,000 tons during WW I.[46] The Republicans became masters of negotiating exceedingly complex arrangements so that inside each of their congressional districts there were more satisfied "winners" than disgruntled "losers". The tariff after 1880 was an ideological relic with no longer any economic rationale.[42]
Cleveland fails to lower the tariff
Democratic President Grover Cleveland redefined the issue in 1887, with his stunning attack on the tariff as inherently corrupt, opposed to true republicanism, and inefficient to boot: "When we consider that the theory of our institutions guarantees to every citizen the full enjoyment of all the fruits of his industry and enterprise... it is plain that the exaction of more than [minimal taxes] is indefensible extortion and a culpable betrayal of American fairness and justice."[47] The election of 1888 was fought primarily over the tariff issue, and Cleveland lost.[48] Republican Congressman William McKinley argued,
"Free foreign trade gives our money, our manufactures, and our markets to other nations to the injury of our labor, our tradespeople, and our farmers. Protection keeps money, markets, and manufactures at home for the benefit of our own people."
Democrats campaigned energetically against the high McKinley tariff of 1890, and scored sweeping gains that year; they restored Cleveland to the White House in 1892. The severe depression that started in 1893 ripped apart the Democratic party. Cleveland and the pro-business Bourbon Democrats insisted on a much lower tariff. His problem was that Democratic electoral successes had brought in Democratic congressmen from industrial districts who were willing to raise rates to benefit their constituents. The Wilson-Gorman Tariff Act of 1894 did lower overall rates from 50 percent to 42 percent, but contained so many concessions to protectionism that Cleveland refused to sign it (it became law anyway).[49]
McKinley elected on high tariff platform
McKinley campaigned heavily in 1896 on the high tariff as a positive solution to depression. Promising protection and prosperity to every economic sector, he won a smashing victory. The Republicans rushed through the Dingley tariff in 1897, boosting rates back to the 50 percent level. Democrats responded that the high rates created government sponsored "trusts" (monopolies) and led to higher consumer prices. McKinley won reelection by an even bigger landslide and started talking about a post-tariff era of reciprocal trade agreements. Reciprocity went nowhere; McKinley's vision was a half century too early.[50]
By about 1900 it had become clear that the U.S. industries were competitive (or more) in nearly all areas and as the need for protection tariffs to pay for the Civil War receded tariffs were gradually reduced. The next peak in tariffs was in about 1918 when World War I expenditures had to be paid for. The next peak in tariffs was due to the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 at the start of the Great Depression.
Republican President Theodore Roosevelt (1901-1909) saw the tariff issue was ripping his party apart, so he postponed any consideration of it. The delicate balance flew apart on president William Howard Taft's watch. Taft campaigned for president in 1908 for tariff "reform", which everyone assumed meant lower rates. The House lowered rates with the Payne Bill, then sent it to the Senate where Nelson Wilmarth Aldrich worked his sleight of hand. Whereas Aldrich was a New England businessman and a master of the complexities of the tariff, the Midwestern Republican insurgents were rhetoricians and lawyers who distrusted the special interests and assumed the tariff was "sheer robbery" at the expense of the ordinary consumer. Rural America believed that its superior morality deserved special protection, while the dastardly immorality of the trusts—and cities generally—merited financial punishment. Aldrich baited them. Did the insurgents want lower tariffs? His wickedly clever Payne-Aldrich Tariff Act of 1909 lowered the protection on Midwestern farm products, while raising rates favorable to his Northeast.[51][52]
Tariff with Canada
The Canadian-American Reciprocity Treaty increased trade between 1855 and its ending in 1866. When it ended Canada turned to tariffs. The National Policy was a Canadian economic program introduced by John A. Macdonald's Conservative Party in 1879 after it returned to power. It had been an official policy, however, since 1876. It was based on high tariffs to protect Canada's manufacturing industry. Macdonald campaigned on the policy in the 1878 election, and handily beat the Liberal Party, which supported free trade.
Efforts to restore free trade with Canada collapsed when Canada rejected a proposed reciprocity treaty in fear of American imperialism in the 1911 federal election. Taft negotiated a reciprocity agreement with Canada, that had the effect of sharply lowering tariffs. Democrats supported the plan but Midwestern Republicans bitterly opposed it. Barnstorming the country for his agreement, Taft undiplomatically pointed to the inevitable integration of the North American economy, and suggested that Canada should come to a "parting of the ways" with Britain. Canada's Conservative Party, under the leadership of Robert Borden, now had an issue to regain power from the low-tariff Liberals; after a surge of pro-imperial anti-Americanism, the Conservatives won. Ottawa rejected reciprocity, reasserted the National Policy and went to London first for new financial and trade deals. The Payne Aldrich Tariff of 1909 actually changed little and had slight economic impact one way or the other, but the political impact was enormous. The insurgents felt tricked and defeated and swore vengeance against Wall Street and its minions Taft and Aldrich. The insurgency led to a fatal split down the middle in 1912 as the GOP lost its balance wheel.[53]
Smuggling and Coast Guard
Historically, high tariffs have led to high rates of smuggling. The United States Revenue Cutter Service was established by Secretary Hamilton in 1790 as an armed maritime law and custom enforcement service. Today it remains the primary maritime law enforcement force in the United States.
The U.S. Customs and Border Protection (CBP) is a federal law enforcement agency of the United States Department of Homeland Security charged with regulating and facilitating international trade, collecting customs (import duties or tariffs approved by the U.S. Congress), and enforcing U.S. regulations, including trade, customs and immigration. They man most border crossing stations and ports. When shipments of goods arrive at a border crossing or port, customs officers inspect the contents and charge a tax according to the tariff formula for that product. Usually the goods cannot continue on their way until the custom duty is paid. Custom duties are one the easiest taxes to collect, and the cost of collection is small.
1913 to present
Woodrow Wilson made a drastic lowering of tariff rates a major priority for his presidency. The 1913 Underwood Tariff cut rates, but the coming of World War I in 1914 radically revised trade patterns. Reduced trade and, especially, the new revenues generated by the federal income tax (bolstered by the ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment in 1913) made tariffs much less important in terms of economic impact and political rhetoric. When the Republicans regained power after the war they restored the usual high rates, with the Fordney-McCumber Tariff of 1922. When the Great Depression hit, international trade shrank drastically. The crisis baffled the GOP, and it unwisely tried to raise tariffs again with the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930. This time it backfired, as Canada, Britain, Germany, France and other industrial countries retaliated with their own tariffs and special, bilateral trade deals. American imports and exports both went into a tailspin. Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Dealers made promises about lowering tariffs on a reciprocal country-by-country basis (which they did), hoping this would expand foreign trade (which it did not.) Frustrated, they gave much more attention to domestic remedies for the depression; by 1936 the tariff issue had faded from politics, and the revenue it raised was small. In World War II both tariffs and reciprocity were insignificant compared to trade channeled through Lend Lease.[54]
Trade liberalization
Tariffs up to the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act of 1930, were set by Congress after many months of testimony and negotiations. In 1934, the U.S. Congress, in a rare delegation of authority, passed the Reciprocal Tariff Act of 1934, which authorized the executive branch to negotiate bilateral tariff reduction agreements with other countries. The prevailing view then was that trade liberalization may help stimulate economic growth. However, no one country was willing to liberalize unilaterally. Between 1934 and 1945, the executive branch negotiated over 32 bilateral trade liberalization agreements with other countries. The belief that low tariffs led to a more prosperous country are now the predominant belief with some exceptions. Multilateralism is embodied in the seven tariff reduction rounds that occurred between 1948 and 1994. In each of these "rounds", all General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) members came together to negotiate mutually agreeable trade liberalization packages and reciprocal tariff rates. In the Uruguay round in 1994, the World Trade Organization (WTO) was established to help establish uniform tariff rates.
Presently only about 30% of all import goods are subject to tariffs in the United States, the rest are on the free list. The "average" tariffs now charged by the United States are at a historic low. The list of negotiated tariffs are listed on the Harmonized Tariff Schedule as put out by the United States International Trade Commission.[55]
Post World War II
After the war the U.S. promoted the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) established in 1947, to minimize tariffs and other restrictions, and to liberalize trade among all capitalist countries. In 1995 GATT became the World Trade Organization (WTO); with the collapse of Communism its open markets/low tariff ideology became dominant worldwide in the 1990s.
American industry and labor prospered after World War II, but hard times set in after 1970. For the first time there was stiff competition from low-cost producers around the globe. Many rust belt industries faded or collapsed, especially the manufacture of steel, TV sets, shoes, toys, textiles and clothing. Toyota and Nissan threatened the giant domestic auto industry. In the late 1970s Detroit and the auto workers union combined to fight for protection. They obtained not high tariffs, but a voluntary restriction of imports from the Japanese government. Quotas were two-country diplomatic agreements that had the same protective effect as high tariffs, but did not invite retaliation from third countries. By limiting the number of Japanese automobiles that could be imported, quotas inadvertently helped Japanese companies push into larger, and more expensive market segments. The Japanese producers, limited by the number of cars they could export to America, opted to increase the value of their exports to maintain revenue growth. This action threatened the American producers' historical hold on the mid- and large-size car markets.[56]
The Chicken tax was a 1964 response by President Lyndon B. Johnson to tariffs placed by Germany (then West Germany) on importation of US chicken. Beginning in 1962, during the President Kennedy administration, the US accused Europe of unfairly restricting imports of American poultry at the request of West German chicken farmers. Diplomacy failed,[57] and in January 1964, two months after taking office, President Johnson retaliated by imposing a 25 percent tax on all imported light trucks. This directly affected the German built Volkswagen vans. Officially it was explained that the light trucks tax would offset the dollar amount of imports of Volkswagen vans from West Germany with the lost American sales of chickens to Europe. But audio tapes from the Johnson White House, reveal that in January 1964, President Johnson was attempting to convince United Auto Workers's president Walter Reuther, not to initiate a strike just prior the 1964 election and to support the president's civil rights platform. Reuther in turn wanted Johnson to respond to Volkswagen's increased shipments to the United States.[58]
1980s to present
The GOP under Ronald Reagan and George H. W. Bush abandoned the protectionist ideology, and came out against quotas and in favor of the GATT/WTO policy of minimal economic barriers to global trade. Free trade with Canada came about as a result of the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement of 1987, which led in 1994 to the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). It was based on Reagan's plan to enlarge the scope of the market for American firms to include Canada and Mexico. President Bill Clinton, with strong Republican support in 1993, pushed NAFTA through Congress over the vehement objection of labor unions.[59][60]
Likewise, in 2000 Clinton worked with Republicans to give China entry into WTO and "most favored nation" trading status (i.e., the same low tariffs promised to any other WTO member). NAFTA and WTO advocates promoted an optimistic vision of the future, with prosperity to be based on intellectuals skills and managerial know-how more than on routine hand labor. They promised that free trade meant lower prices for consumers. Opposition to liberalized trade came increasingly from labor unions, who argued that this system also meant lower wages and fewer jobs for American workers who could not compete against wages of less than a dollar an hour. The shrinking size and diminished political clout of these unions repeatedly left them on the losing side.[61]
Despite overall decreases in international tariffs, some tariffs have been more resistant to change. For example, due partially to tariff pressure from the European Common Agricultural Policy, US agricultural subsidies have seen little decrease over the past few decades, even in the face of recent pressure from the WTO during the latest Doha talks.[62]
See also
Further reading
- Bils, Mark. "Tariff protection and production in the early US cotton textile industry." Journal of Economic History (1984) 44#4 pp: 1033-1045.
- Dewey, Davis Rich. Financial History of the United States (5th ed. 1915) online full text
- Doran, Charles F. and Gregory P. Marchildon. The NAFTA Puzzle: Political Parties and Trade in North America (1994)
- Eckes, Alfred. Opening America's Market: U.S. Foreign Trade Policy since 1776 (1995)
- Elliott, Orrin Leslie. The Tariff Controversy in the United States 1789-1833: With a Summary of the Period Before the Adoption of the Constitution (1892) online
- Hawke, Gary R. "The United States tariff and industrial protection in the late nineteenth century." Economic History Review (1975) 28#1 pp: 84-99.
- Hill, William. "Colonial Tariffs," Quarterly Journal of Economics (1892) 7#1 pp. 78–100 in JSTOR
- Hofstadter, Richard. "The Tariff Issue on the Eve of the Civil War", The American Historical Review Vol. 44, No. 1 (Oct., 1938), pp. 50–55 full text in JSTOR
- Irwin, Douglas A. "Antebellum Tariff Politics: Regional Coalitions and Shifting Economic Interests", Journal of Law and Economics, 51 (Nov. 2008), 715–42.
- Lake, David A. "International economic structures and American foreign economic policy, 1887-1934." World Politics (1983) 35#4 pp: 517-543. online
- Kaplan, Edward S.; Prelude to Trade Wars: American Tariff Policy, 1890–1922 Greenwood Press 1994
- Kaplan, Edward S. American Trade Policy: 1923–1995 (1996), online review
- Narton, John H. Judith L. Goldstein, Timothy E. Josling, and Richard H. Steinberg, The Evolution of the Trade Regime: Politics, Law, and Economics of the GATT and the WTO (2008)
- Schattsneider, E. E. Politics, Pressures and the Tariff (1935). Passage of Hawley-Smoot tariff
- Smith, Mark A. The Tariff on Wool 1926
- Stanwood, Edward (1903). American tariff controversies in the nineteenth century. Houghton, Mifflin. detailed political narrative; full text online
- Studenski, Paul & Herman Edward Krooss (2003). Financial History of the United States. Beard Books.
- Summers; Festus P. William L. Wilson and Tariff Reform, a Biography (1953) on 1890s
- Taussig, F. W. Some Aspects of the Tariff Question: An Examination of the Development of American Industries Under Protection (1931) online
- Taussig, F. W. The Tariff History of the United States. 8th edition (1931); 5th edition 1910 is online, the standard scholarly history; it collects articles he wrote in the journals another copy
- Taussig, F.W. "Tariff", Encyclopædia Britannica (11th edition, 1911) vol 26; online
- Taussig, Frank William. The history of the present tariff, 1860-1883 (1885) online
- Taussig, Frank W. "The Tariff, 1830-1860." Quarterly Journal of Economics (1888) 2#3 pp: 314-346. in JSTOR
- Taylor, George Rogers, ed. The Great Tariff Debate, 1820–1830 (1953), excerpts from primary and secondary sources
- Terrill, Tom E. The Tariff, Politics, and American Foreign Policy 1874–1901 (1973).
- Turney, Elaine C. Prange, and Cynthia Clark Northrup. Tariffs and Trade in U.S. History: An Encyclopedia (3 vol 2003); primary sources in vol 3
- Wolman, Paul. Most Favored Nation: The Republican Revisionists and U.S. Tariff Policy, 1897–1912 (1992)
Notes
- ↑ Historical Statistics of the United States 1789-1945; Series M-42-55; Imports (1789-1945), Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Bicentennial Edition Historical Statistics of the United States Series {Part 2 Zip file: CT1970p2-08;} Series U 1 25; Balance of International Payments Imports 1790 1970 Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Imports 1960-2010 Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Historical Statistics of the United States 1789-1945 Series P 89-98 Excise Tax {labeled: Internal Revenue/Other} Tot. Receipts; Customs, Income taxes Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Whitehouse Historical Tables 1940-2016; Table 1.1 Tot. Receipts (1901-2010); Table 2-1, 2-4 Excise Tax(1934-2010); Table 2-5 Customs (1940-2010) Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970 {Part 2 Zip file: CT1970p2-12;} Series Y 343-351 (1940-1970) Customs, Tot. Receipts, Income taxes; Payroll taxes, Excise; Y342 339 (1940 1970) Receipts; Y-352 357(1789-1939) Government Receipts: Total(1789-1970), Customs (1789-1970), Y 358 373 Excise tax (1863-1970) Income Tax (1916-1970); Series U 1-25 Balance of International Payments Imports(1790-1970) Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Historical Statistics of the United States Series 1790-1945 Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Bicentennial Edition Historical Statistics of the United States Series 1790-1970 Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ U.S. Census Trade Statistic Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ Whitehouse Historical Tables 1940-2016 Accessed 5 Aug 2011
- ↑ William Hill, "Colonial Tariffs," Quarterly Journal of Economics (1892) 7#1 pp. 78-100 in JSTOR
- ↑ William Smith McClellan (1912). Smuggling in the American colonies at the outbreak of the Revolution: with special reference to the West Indies trade. pp. full text online.
- ↑ John W. Tyler, Smugglers and Patriots: Boston Merchants and the Advent of the American Revolution (1986) online review
- ↑ Dewey, Financial History of the United States (5th ed. 1915) ch 1-3
- ↑ Dewey, Financial History of the United States (5th ed. 1915) ch 4-5
- ↑ Dewey, Financial History of the United States (5th ed. 1915) ch 6-7
- ↑ Douglas A. Irwin, "The Aftermath of Hamilton's 'Report on Manufactures'", Journal of Economic History, Sept 2004, Vol. 64 Issue 3, pp. 800–821
- ↑ Barbara M. Tucker, and Kenneth H. Tucker, Industrializing Antebellum America: The Rise of Manufacturing Entrepreneurs in the Early Republic (2008)
- ↑ Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States (8th edition (1931), ch. 1
- ↑ Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States (8th edition (1931), ch. 2
- ↑ Taussig, Tariff History pp 109-24
- ↑ John A. Moore, "The Grossest and Most Unjust Species of Favoritism: Competing Views of Republican Political Economy: The Tariff Debates of 1841 and 1842", Essays in Economic & Business History (2011) 29: 59–73.
- ↑ Taussig, Tariff History pp 124-54
- ↑ Scott C. James and David E. Lake, "The second face of hegemony: Britain's repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846", International Organization, Winter 1989, Vol. 43 Issue 1, pp. 1–28
- ↑ http://www.usgovernmentrevenue.com/revenue_chart_1840_1861USm_16s1li111mcn_F0f
- ↑ Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States (1931), pp. 123–61
- ↑ Richard Hofstadter, "The Tariff Issue on the Eve of the Civil War", The American Historical Review (1938) 44#1 pp. 50–55 full text in JSTOR
- ↑ Robert Gray Gunderson, Old Gentlemen's Convention: The Washington Peace Conference of 1861 (1961)
- ↑ Mark Thornton and Robert B. Ekelund, Jr., Tariffs, Blockades, and Inflation: The Economics of the Civil War (2004)
- ↑ Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States (1931), pp. 155–70
- ↑ Dewey, Financial History (1915) p 299
- ↑ Paul Studenski; Herman Edward Krooss (2003). Financial History of the United States. Beard Books. p. 157.
- ↑ Howard K. Beale "The Tariff and Reconstruction," American Historical Review (1930) 35#2 pp. 276-294 in JSTOR
- ↑ Hugh Tulloch (1999). The Debate On the American Civil War Era. Manchester UP. p. 226.
- ↑ Stanley Coben, "Northeastern Business and Radical Reconstruction: A Re-Examination." Mississippi Valley Historical Review (1959): 67-90. in JSTOR
- ↑ Thomas J. Pressly, "Andrew Johnson and Reconstruction (review)" Civil War History (1961) 7#1 pp. 91-92 online
- ↑ Paul H. Tedesco, Patriotism, Protection, and Prosperity: James Moore Swank, the American Iron and Steel Association, and the Tariff, 1873-1913 (Garland, 1985.)
- ↑ John Ashworth (1987). 'Agrarians' and 'Aristocrats': Party Political Ideology in the United States, 1837-1846. Cambridge University Press. p. 252.
- ↑ Joanne R. Reitano, The Tariff Question in the Gilded Age: The Great Debate of 1888 (Penn State Press, 1994)
- ↑ H. Wayne Morgan, William McKinley and His America (1965)
- ↑ F. W. Taussig, "The McKinley Tariff Act." The Economic Journal (1891) 1#2 pp: 326-350. in JSTOR
- 1 2 Tom E. Terrill, The Tariff, Politics, and American Foreign Policy 1874-1901 (1973)
- ↑ Douglas A. Fisher, Steel Serves the Nation,U.S. Steel, 1951, p. 15
- ↑ Frank William Taussig (1931). The Tariff History of the United States. pp. 192, 293.
- ↑ F. W. Taussig, The Tariff History Of The United States, 1909 edition, p. 259
- ↑ Douglas A. Fisher, Steel Serves the Nation,U.S. Steel, 1951, p. 48
- ↑ Springer, ed., William M. (1892). Tariff reform, the paramount issue: Speeches and writings on the questions involved in the presidential contest of 1892. p. 391.
- ↑ H. Wayne Morgan, From Hayes to McKinley: National Party Politics, 1877–1896 (1969)
- ↑ Festus P. Summers, William L. Wilson and Tariff Reform, a Biography (1953)
- ↑ Harold U. Faulkner, Politics, Reform, and Expansion, 1890–1900 (1959)
- ↑ David W. Detzer, "Businessmen, Reformers, and Tariff Revision: The Payne-Aldrich Tariff of 1909", Historian, (1973) 35#2 pp. 196–204, online
- ↑ Stanley D. Solvick, "William Howard Taft and the Payne-Aldrich Tariff," Mississippi Valley Historical Review (1963) 50#3 pp. 424-442 in JSTOR
- ↑ Paolo Enrico Coletta, The Presidency of William Howard Taft (1973)
- ↑ Edward S. Kaplan, American Trade Policy: 1923–1995 (1996)
- ↑ Harmonized Tariff Schedule Accessed 12 Jul 2011
- ↑ John H. Barton, Judith L. Goldstein, Timothy E. Josling, and Richard H. Steinberg, The Evolution of the Trade Regime: Politics, Law, and Economics of the GATT and the WTO (2008)
- ↑ "The Big Three's Shameful Secret". Freetrade.org, Daniel J. Ikenson, July 6, 2003. Archived from the original on 2012-07-31.
- ↑ "Light Trucks Increase Profits But Foul Air More than Cars". The New York Times, Keith Bradsher, November 30, 1997. November 30, 1997.
- ↑ Gary Chaison (2005). Unions in America. SAGE. p. 151.
- ↑ Kenneth F. Warren (2008). Encyclopedia of U.S. Campaigns, Elections, and Electoral Behavior. SAGE Publications. p. 358.
- ↑ Barton, et al. The Evolution of the Trade Regime: Politics, Law, and Economics of the GATT and the WTO (2008)
- ↑ Congressional Research Service report
External links
- lesson plan on tariffs in US history from Northern Illinois University
- Campaign Songs as Propaganda: Free Trade vs. Protectionism — In Whose Interest? from Northern Illinois University